Production and reproduction are ways of talking about our relationship to the future. Both terms address a kind of world-building art, one that aims to create a future in which “we” – defined in a way that our notions of production and reproduction may themselves stipulate – can thrive or at least survive. They entail a providence that takes measures in the present, either to create objects for later consumption or to create people who will mature and, when they reach the age of maturity, will consume, produce, and reproduce in their turn.
We treat production and reproduction as distinctive social processes because of the way that capitalism distinguishes between people and commodities: people as sources of value (by purchasing or, more importantly, by freely selling their labor power), commodities as carriers or signifiers of value. In an agricultural slave society like the Roman Empire, though, the lines between production and reproduction get so blurry that the distinction between the two may not be analytically useful. Romans sometimes treat people as commodities, as carriers of value, while animals appear in Roman natural history as “sources” of value in sometimes a very literal sense.*
Can we trace Pliny’s analogy between (servile) human reproduction and the birth of pearls to this “confusion?” My answer is a qualified “yes:” Pliny has no good economic reason to treat slaves and pearls as essentially different in the way that we distinguish between people and commodities. And Pliny’s Natural History is, among other things, a textbook of Roman economics.
A qualified “yes,” however, because this explanation only shows why Pliny might think of pearls and people as similar kinds of things, both commodities carrying value. We still need to understand why it is that they carry the very different values that they do. Why are pearls precious qua unique (unio), while humans become more valuable when they’re identical (unitas of two or more?)
One obvious answer to that question would invoke the relative scarcity of the two goods: identical people who aren’t identical twins are about as hard to find as pearls, while “unique” human beings are a dime a dozen. However, “scarcity” describes a state of affairs without explaining it. What can we say about the economy or world-system or Empire that produces exactly this set of scarcity relations?
I think that, in an odd way, it mirrors a sense of inside/outside that was as important to the self-esteem of Roman elites as it was to the constitution of the Roman economy. Outside the boundaries of the Empire, Roman wealth could “command” the production or extraction of difficult-to-acquire goods whose value lay primarily in their rarity.** Pearls are both an example of this type of good – they come from the Red Sea and points beyond, they are guarded by sharks, the oysters themselves will bite off your hand if you let them – and a paradigm for it – as something unique, each pearl’s rarity is absolute.
On the other hand, Pliny and other authors regard “domestic” production from within the bounds of the Empire according to an ethic of abundance. The whole point of having an Empire, after all, is to make sure you never run short of anything. This is of course a very Rome-centric perspective: tribute and taxation bring goods from all over the Empire to the city of Rome, but provincials or even small farmers elsewhere in Italy would probably not have felt such a sense of abundance.***
Goods from anywhere in the Empire were available to Roman elites. The two identical slave children provided by Toranius to Marc Antony are paradigmatic of this availability in much the same way as pearls are paradigmatic of the scarcity of “foreign” luxuries. Coming from opposite ends of the Empire – in fact, from almost the utmost boundaries of Roman rule during the late Republic – they demonstrate the power of Roman elites to extract commodities from anywhere that Rome holds sway. So these children are paradigmatic – but not exemplary, since the pair of them, on account of their unitas, are not cheap and abundant but rather rare and scarce.
What is it about these children that puts them in the same realm of value as pearls, those paradigmatic and exemplary items of foreign exchange? One approach to answering that question would begin by asking how large a population, or an Empire, has to be before two unrelated but identical people appear in it. The answer would give us some way of evaluating Pliny’s subjective sense of the Empire’s magnitude – in one sense, “very big.” In another, “about the size of an oyster.” Through its bigness, Rome too becomes capable of producing pearls of great price.
Now let’s return to the problem of building a future. What’s the future towards which this parable of production and reproduction points? A full response to that question, which would have to take into account the self-conscious pastness of Pliny’s anecdote about Toranius and Marc Antony, as well as the Civil War toward which it points, is beyond the scope of this blog post. Nonetheless, the broad outlines of an answer are already visible. The Empire takes care of the survival of Roman elites; their task of self-production, which the Empire also enables, will be to acquire unique luxury goods and thereby to make themselves “unique” in a sense that transcends the uniqueness which Pliny already takes to be part of the human condition.
* Pliny says of a number of animals whose body parts circulate as luxury goods in the roman world that they “know for what reason they’re hunted” vel sim., and that they act accordingly – either to surrender the valuable part or to hide it from human beans. Here and elsewhere in the Roman animal imaginary, critters share our economic sense of what’s valuable.
** But see Matthew FitzPatrick’s “Provincializing Rome” for a discussion of how this relationship might have looked from the perspective of Rome’s trading partners in the East.
*** The major exceptions to this division between scarce foreign and abundant domestic production in Rome are gold and silver – precisely the metals that constitute Rome’s money supply. I’ve seen some interesting preliminary work on this problem from a colleague and will share it here when it’s published.